Populations Past atlas
Overview
Last updated: 10th May 2024.
The second half of the nineteenth century was a period of major change in the dynamics of the British population. This was a time of transition from a relatively 'high pressure' demographic regime characterised by medium to high birth and death rates to a 'low pressure' regime of relatively low birth and death rates, a transformation known as the 'demographic transition'. This transition was not uniform across England and Wales: certain places and social groups appear to have led the declines while others lagged behind. Exploring these geographical patterns can provide insights into the process of change and the influence of economic and geographical factors.
This website allows users to create and view maps of different demographic measures and related socio-economic indicators every 10 years between 1851 and 1911. These include fertility, childhood mortality, marriage, migration status, household compositions, age-structure, occupational status and population density. Brief explanations of each measure are included, indicating how they are calculated and explaining how they relate to other measures. Users can zoom in to a particular area on the map to compare side by side maps of different times or measures. When large areas are viewed the data for England and Wales are displayed in Registration Districts (RDs), but the display changes to Registration Sub-Districts (RSDs) when the users zoom in. Scottish data are only available at RD level, although the team have created smaller subdivisions for the larger cities. The data for the smallest geographical units underlying the maps can be downloaded using an 'export' button.
Geographic units
The main geographical units used in these maps are Registration Sub-Districts (RSDs) for England and Wales and Registration Districts (RDs) for Scotland. These were units used to report both census outputs and vital statistics (births, marriages and deaths) between 1851 and 1911. In England and Wales there were about 2,000 RSDs in each of the census years shown, ranging in area from fewer than 30 acres to well over 100,000 acres, and in population size from a few hundred people to 150,000 persons or more. For Scotland we have used 556 RDs or amalgamations of RDs whose boundaries did not change significantly between 1851 and 1901. RDs in Scotland ranged in area from around 64 to over 650,000 acres, the larger areas reflecting the low population density in many parts of the country. RD populations in Scotland ranged from a few hundred to over 900,000. Those containing very small populations were merged with a contiguous unit. For the five largest urban areas (Edinburgh, Glasgow, Aberdeen, Dundee and Paisley) we have split the single RD which covered each into a number of smaller sub-city units.
RSDs/RDs which were predominantly urban tended to be smaller and more populous, and therefore had higher population densities than rural RSDs/RDs. However not all RSDs/RDs covered a uniformly urban or uniformly rural area: some contained both part of a town and some of the surrounding area, while others which were mainly countryside included settlements of varying sizes. The Scottish units used here remain spatially stable, but although the boundaries of many English and Welsh RSDs encompassed the same areas from one year to the next, there was a considerable amount of re-drawing of the boundaries over time. There is therefore a different number of English and Welsh RSDs at each of our observation points. There was a particularly large amount of change between the 1891 and 1901 census, when many urban RSDs were merged to form larger units.
Boundary data: Because there was considerable boundary change between each census, the English and Welsh maps use a unique set of boundaries for each census year. The boundaries shown in the online version of the maps have been considerably simplified to speed up the graphic display process. If you would like to use the original, more geographically precise, boundaries, you can download the Scottish data from https://doi.org/10.17863/CAM.94398. Please contact campop@geog.cam.ac.uk for the English and Welsh boundary data. In the explanatory text we present figures for England, Scotland and Wales separately, all three countries combined (GB), and for eight groups of RSDs within GB and within each of the three constituent countries (see Type of Place for an explanation). Due to the absence of England and Wales for 1871 we do not show GB figures for that year. Similarly we do not have data for Scotland in 1911, so we don't show GB figures for 1911 either. Because England's population was so much larger than that of either Scotland or Wales, the GB figures mainly reflect what was happening in England.
Citation for English and Welsh map usage: Day, J.D. Registration sub-district boundaries for England and Wales 1851-1911 (2016). This dataset was created by the 'Atlas of Victorian Fertility Decline' project (PI: A.M. Reid) with funding from the ESRC (ES/L015463/1). The Day dataset has been created using Satchell, A.E.M., Kitson, P.M.K., Newton, G.H., Shaw-Taylor, L., and Wrigley E.A., 1851 England and Wales census parishes, townships and places (2016) available at: https://www.geog.cam.ac.uk/research/projects/occupations/datasets/documentation.html. The Satchell et al dataset is an enhanced version of Burton, N, Westwood J., and Carter P., GIS of the ancient parishes of England and Wales, 1500-1850. Colchester, Essex: UK Data Archive (May 2004), SN 4828, which is a GIS version of Kain, R.J.P., and Oliver, R.R., Historic parishes of England and Wales: An electronic map of boundaries before 1850 with a gazetteer and metadata. Colchester, Essex: UK Data Archive, May, 2001. SN 4348.
Citation for Scottish map usage: Satchell, A. (2023). Consistent Scottish registration district boundaries with subdivisions in large towns, 1851‒1901. Apollo - University of Cambridge Repository https://doi.org/10.17863/CAM.94398.
Data
The measures shown in the maps on this website have mainly been derived from the computerised individual level census enumerators' books (and household schedules for 1911) for England and Wales and Scotland enhanced under the I-CeM project. See Schürer, K. and Higgs, E. (2014). Integrated Census Microdata (I-CeM), 1851-1911. [data collection]. Colchester, Essex: UK Data Archive [distributor]. SN: 7481, http://dx.doi.org/10.5255/UKDA-SN-7481-1. The English and Welsh I-CeM does not currently include data for 1871, and although the project has been able to access a version of the data for that year it does not contain the information necessary to calculate many of the variables presented here. Users should therefore beware of the missing time points on many of the graphs provided. The Scottish I-CeM does not currently include data for 1911, although it is hoped that this will be added in time.
Additional data, for some indicators, has been derived from the civil registration of birth, deaths and marriage, which was introduced in England and Wales in 1837 and in Scotland in 1855. For England and Wales we transcribed parts of the tables summarising these events by year and RSD, which were published by the Registrar General in his quarterly, annual and decennial reports of births, deaths and marriages. For Scotland we derived numbers of births and early age deaths from the database created by the Digitising Scotland project. Summary mortality data for both England and Wales and Scotland were taken from the Human Mortality Database, www.mortality.org.
Place characteristics
Type of place
Definition: Each geographic unit (Registration Sub-District or Registration District) has been assigned to one of eight types of place based on its occupational structure and population density. The types of place are: AGRICULTURE, SEMI-RURAL, SEMI-PROFESSIONAL, PROFESSIONAL, TEXTILE, MINING, TRANSPORT, and OTHER URBAN.
Calculation: For each RSD, all economically active men and women (excluding general labourers) aged between 15 and 64 were identified. The percentage of these who worked in each of the following occupational orders was calculated: mining, metal work/manufacture, textiles, agriculture, pottery, professions, services, and transport. These percentages were then used to allocate each place as follows:
- If >= 25% work in textiles then the place was designated TEXTILE
- Otherwise if >=30% worked in mining or metals then the place was designated MINING
- Otherwise if >=7.5% worked in the professions AND >=30% worked in services then the place was designated PROFESSIONAL
- Otherwise if >=5% worked in agriculture AND population density <1 person per acre then the place was designated AGRICULTURE
- Otherwise if >=5% worked in agriculture then the place was designated SEMI-RURAL
- Otherwise if >=15% worked in transport then the place was designated TRANSPORT
- Otherwise if >=7.5% worked in the professions then the place was designated SEMI-PROFESSIONAL
- Otherwise the place was designated OTHER URBAN
This exercise was carried out separately for each year, allowing places to change character as economic development took place. NB: for England and Wales 1871, occupational structure was not available, so type of place was assigned using 1861 and 1881 for the same areas, and this may account for some discontinuities in the series.
See also: Population Density; Social Class.
Overview: In terms of area, Britain was still predominantly agricultural in the late nineteenth and early twentieth centuries. However agricultural areas were sparsely populated: the bulk of the population already lived in towns and cities. In the years leading up to the dawn of the twentieth century the process of urbanisation continued, so that by 1901 over 80 per cent of the population of England and Wales lived in urban areas. Urban populations could grow by three different processes: natural increase (an excess of births over deaths) in urban areas, migration of rural-dwellers into towns and cities, or the re-classification of areas as urban. This last process, 'extension' or 'urban sprawl', was predominantly due to the expansion of the built-up area into the surrounding countryside. If people moved out of crowded city centres to more thinly populated suburbs then this process could be associated with a decline in the population density of inner-city areas. The maps, and the graph of the number of acres covered by different types of place, show the latter process clearly, with the gradual spread of non-green colours across the maps indicating change in the character of areas. This is particularly noticeable in the area around London: PROFESSIONAL and SEMI-PROFESSIONAL areas can be seen to radiate out from the city with the passage of time.
Although the growth of PROFESSIONAL places is particularly noticeable on the maps, it was actually the SEMI-PROFESSIONAL places which saw the largest increase in their population. There were over 9 million people living in British AGRICULTURAL areas in 1851, but this number had declined by 1.3 million people by 1901; a fall of around 14 per cent, but because the total population of the three countries almost doubled over the same period, the percentage of the total population living in AGRICULTURAL areas fell from 45 to 22 per cent.
Examination of the maps shows that some of the types of area were very geographically concentrated, notably TEXTILE and MINING areas. Others, such as TRANSPORT and OTHER URBAN were spread around the country and are harder to identify on the maps.
Population density
Definition: Population density is the number of people per acre (one acre is 4047 square metres, which is a little larger than half a football field).
Calculation: Population density has been calculated using the number of people enumerated in each RSD/RD on census night as published in the census report for each census year, and the area of the RSD/RD derived from the GIS of RSD/RD boundaries.
Please note: The population density categories shown on the maps are not all the same size.
See also: Type of Place.
Overview: England, Wales and Scotland had very different levels of population density, with the highest levels in England and the lowest in Scotland. Towns and cities are generally more densely populated than rural areas, so the maps of this measure can be used to indicate the location of urban areas across the country. Within urban areas, however, there was considerable variation in population density. Zooming in on London, for example, shows that the East End was much more densely populated than the West End where the wealthier people tended to live in larger houses, with more space between them. Suburbs were generally less densely populated than the inner cities. MINING areas tended to be relatively sparsely populated as they often consisted of collections of pit villages rather than towns or cities.
Please note: People living in a Registration Sub-District (RSD) or Registration District (RD) which encompassed both urban and rural areas were more likely to have lived in the urban part than the rural part, but the reported population density is calculated as an average for the whole unit.
The population of Britain was increasing very rapidly in the second half of the nineteenth century. Between 1851 and 1911 the population of England and Wales more than doubled, rising from just under 18 million to just over 36 million. Over a slightly shorter period (1851 to 1901) the population of Scotland increased from just under 3 million to nearly 4.5 million. An increasing population in a fixed area means that population density in both England and Wales also doubled, from 0.52 to 1.05 and from 0.23 to 0.47 persons per acre respectively, and that in Scotland also increased, but not as fast. However, the additional people were not spread evenly across the country as population increase was accompanied by rapid urbanisation. The graphs below showing population density (note that the scale differs by type of place) and the graphs showing the areas covered by the different types of place (see Type of Place variable) indicate that although MINING and TEXTILE places were increasing in population density, it was urban areas of other, various types which saw increases in the area they covered. The growth of new urban and suburban areas seems to have been a more important part of urbanisation in the late nineteenth century than was the crowding of more people into the existing footprint of towns and cities.
Fertility variables
The easiest measure of fertility to calculate is the Crude Birth Rate (CBR) which is the number of births in a year, per 1,000 people alive in the middle of that year. The CBRs in England and Wales and Scotland fell dramatically over the last few decades of the nineteenth century and into the twentieth century, decreasing from around 35 births per 1,000 people in the 1860s and 1870s when fertility was at its maximum to 15 births per 1,000 people in England and Wales, and 17 in Scotland, in the early 1930s when it reached a nadir not achieved again until the 1970s. However the CBR is a very poor measure of child-bearing experience. In the first place it is often distorted by changes in mortality and the age-structure of the population, a particularly pertinent issue in the late nineteenth century when mortality was also in rapid decline. For example if there are fewer women in the childbearing ages, then the CBR will be lower, even if each woman is having the same number of children. The Legitimate and Illegitimate Birth Rates, also provided here, to some extent solve this problem by relating the numbers of births (legitimate and illegitimate) to the numbers of women 'at risk' of giving birth, i.e. married and unmarried women in the fertile ages (age 15-49). Even these birth rates, however, tell us nothing about the way that family-building patterns changed as women aged. In particular they do not tell us whether fewer children were born because women delayed the start of their child-bearing career, began to have larger gaps between their children, or stopped having children at a younger age on average. These sorts of questions can only be answered using data which give the age of the mother at the time of the child's birth, and until now such data has not been available for this crucial period of Britain's demographic history.
This project use the following set of fertility measures:
- Total Fertility Rate: the average number of children per woman, irrespective of marital status.
- Total Marital Fertility Rate: the average number of children per married woman.
- Legitimate Birth Rate: the number of legitimate births divided by the number of married women in the childbearing ages.
- Illegitimate Birth Rate: the number of illegitimate births divided by the number of unmarried women in the childbearing ages (which are sometimes taken as 15-49, sometimes 20-49).
- Illegitimacy Ratio: the percentage of all births which are illegitimate.
Total Fertility Rate (TFR)
Definition: The Total Fertility Rate (TFR) is an estimate of the average number of children a woman gives birth to between her 20th birthday and her 50th birthday (written '20-49' to show her 'age in completed years').
Calculation: There are no sources which record how many children women had over their lifetime in this historical period, so the TFR has been calculated by assuming that each woman successively experienced the birth-rates of women at each age group observed at a particular point in time. The birth rates of women in each age group are called Age-Specific Fertility Rates (ASFRs) and can be calculated from the census enumerators' books by identifying children and their mothers, working out how many children were born to women of each age in the five years leading up the census, and adjusting for various factors including child mortality and children living away from their mothers.
ASFRs and TFRs have been calculated using a database of the individual level census enumerators' books for each census year originally made available by the I-CeM project and further enhanced by the Atlas project team.
See also: Total Marital Fertility Rate (TMFR); Age at Marriage; Celibacy.
Overview: The Total Fertility Rate (TFR) can be interpreted as the average number of children a woman will give birth to over her life-time. In the mid-19th century, women in Britain had around four and a half children each, although there was considerable geographic variation, with considerably higher fertility in the MINING areas of the North-East of England and parts of Scotland's central belt, and particularly low fertility in the West End of London and much of the Scottish Highlands. By 1911 the national TFR had fallen by a third, and English women were having only three children each. It is important to bear in mind that many women remained unmarried and without any children at all, and this reduces the average number of children borne per woman. In fact, much of the geographical and social difference in TFR is due to different patterns of marriage (see Age of Marriage, Celibacy). Although increases in the age at marriage towards the end of the nineteenth century did contribute to falling fertility, the major driver of the fertility decline was a decline in marital fertility, shown by a related measure, the Total Marital Fertility Rate (TMFR).
Total Marital Fertility Rate (TMFR)
Definition: The Total Marital Fertility Rate (TMFR) is the number of children a woman would give birth to if she married at age 20 and remained married (without her husband dying) until her 50th birthday (written '20-49' to show her 'age in completed years').
Calculation: There are no sources for Britain which record how many children women had over their lifetime in this historical period, so the TMFR has been calculated by assuming that each woman successively experienced the observed birth-rates of women at each age group, from age 20 (or 25) until her 50th birthday. The birth rates of women in each age group are called Age-Specific Marital Fertility Rates (ASMFRs) and can be calculated from the census enumerators' books by identifying children and their mothers, working out how many children were born to women of each age in the five years leading up the census, having adjusted for various factors including childhood mortality.
ASMFRs and TMFRs have been calculated using a database of the individual level census enumerators' books for each census year originally made available by the I-CeM project and further enhanced by the Atlas project team.
See also: Total Marital Fertility Rate (TMFR); Legitimate Birth Rate; Age at Marriage; Celibacy.
Overview: The Total Marital Fertility Rate (TMFR) can be interpreted as the average number of children a women would have during her marriage, if she married at age 20 and stayed married until her 50th birthday. It is important to bear in mind that it was unusual for women to marry at such a young age in England and Wales in the nineteenth century, therefore the TMFR should not be interpreted as the experience of a typical married woman. Because the majority of women were over 25 when they married, a more typical experience can be expressed by calculating the number of children a woman would have had if she married at age 25, and this measure, TMFR(25-49), is given in the graph below, alongside the usual measure, TMFR(20-49). This shows that women who married at age 20 had nearly two and a half more children, on average, than did women who married at age 25 (NB The maps show TMFR(20-49)). As can be seen by the trends in the Age at Marriage, marriage age increased in the last couple of decades of the nineteenth century, and this contributed to the decline in overall fertility as measured by the Total Fertility Rate (TFR). However the major driver of the fertility decline was a decline in marital fertility, which decreased by over one child per woman between 1881 and 1911. The fertility transition can therefore be characterised as a change from fertility control by marriage to fertility control within marriage.
Although much of the geographical and social differences in fertility were due to differences in the age of marriage and the propensity to never marry, there were also differences, before fertility started to decline, in fertility rates among those who were married, with high marital fertility in both MINING and AGRICULTURAL areas. Because changes in marital fertility happened earlier in some types of place - notably TEXTILE areas, but also PROFESSIONAL places - and were delayed in others (MINING, TRANSPORT and OTHER URBAN areas) the geographical differences in marital fertility within England increased and within Scotland decreased. Women in Scotland had higher fertility within marriage than those in England, with Wales in between.
Legitimate Birth Rate
Definition: The Legitimate Birth Rate gives the number of legitimate live births in a year per 1,000 married women aged 15-49.
Calculation: For England and Wales, the Legitimate Birth Rate has been calculated using the numbers of legitimate live births for each RSD published in the Registrar General's Annual Reports. In most cases the number of births has been averaged over three years: the year before the census, the census year and the year after the census year, in order to minimise the effect of small numbers. However 1910 was the last year for which data on the number of births by legitimacy was published for RSDs, so for our 1911 figures only births for 1910 were used. In some cases where boundary changes occurred in the three years around a census, the average was calculated using only births from the year where the birth and census data referred to the same RSD. For Scotland the number of births for each RD was obtained from the Digitising Scotland database, and these rates are based on 10 year periods (centred on each census) to minimise the effects of small numbers in some RDs. For both England and Wales and Scotland the number of married women in each RSD/RD was calculated using the individual level census data, inflating the figure by the ratio of the female population in the I-CeM database to the female population for the same RSD/RD published in the census reports. This was done to minimise the impact of data missing from the I-CeM dataset. Scotland did not introduce civil registration until 1855, so this rate cannot be calculated for 1851.
See also: Illegitimate Birth Rate; Total Marital Fertility Rate; Total Fertility Rate.
Overview: At the national level fertility in Britain did not start to fall until the late 1870s or the early 1880s. From then until the 1930s, the number of children born per 1,000 married women fell steadily. Overall the Legitimate Fertility Rate was slightly higher in Scotland than in England, but followed a similar trajectory. The rate for Wales was only marginally higher than that for England until 1880, but then a slower decline in Wales introduced a gap between the two countries. There were also differences in birth rates between different types of place even before the fertility decline, with the highest levels in MINING areas and the lowest levels in PROFESSIONAL places. It is noticeable that the legitimate birth rate in English TEXTILE areas was already falling between 1851 and 1861 - around 30 years earlier than in other types of place. Within each type of place, the Scottish legitimate birth rate was higher than that in England and Wales.
Illegitimate Birth Rate
Definition: The Illegitimate Birth Rate gives the number of illegitimate live births in a year per 1,000 unmarried (i.e. single, divorced and widowed) women aged 15-49.
Calculation: For England and Wales, the Illegitimate Birth Rate is calculated using the numbers of illegitimate live births for each RSD published in the Registrar General's Annual Reports. In most cases the number of births is averaged over three years: the year before the census, the census year and the year after the census year. However 1910 was the last year for which data on the number of births by legitimacy was published for RSDs, so for our 1911 figures only births for 1910 were used. In some cases where boundary changes occurred in the three years around a census, the average was calculated using only births from the year where the birth and census data referred to the same RSD. For Scotland the number of births for each RD was obtained from the Digitising Scotland database, and these rates are based on 10 year periods (centred on each census) to minimise the effects of small numbers in some RDs. For all three countries the numbers of single, divorced and widowed women in each RSD/RD were calculated using the individual level census data, inflating the figure by the ratio of the female population in the I-CeM database to the female population for the same RSD/RD published in the census reports. This was done to minimise the impact of data missing from the ICeM dataset. Scotland did not introduce civil registration until 1855, so this rate cannot be calculated for 1851.
See also: Illegitimacy ratio; Legitimate birth rate
Overview: Illegitimacy was not uncommon in historic Britain: in the mid-nineteenth century there were nearly 20 illegitimate births for every 1,000 unmarried women in England and Wales, and closer to 25 in Scotland. However the risks of a woman having a child out of marriage fell by around half in the Victorian era, to less than 8 illegitimate births per 1,000 unmarried women in England and just under 9 in Wales in 1911 and to 17 in Scotland in 1901. In the British past, illegitimate fertility often varied with legitimate fertility - in other words when people married young and had many children within marriage, they were also more likely to have had children before they got married. This relationship is also evident in the nineteenth century geographic patterns of legitimate and illegitimate fertility: MINING areas had high legitimate and illegitimate birth rates, whereas PROFESSIONAL areas had low rates of both. TEXTILE areas witnessed earlier declines in both type of fertility although illegitimate birth rates fell noticeably faster than legitimate in the early years.
Illegitimacy Ratio
Definition: The Illegitimacy Ratio gives the number of illegitimate births as a percentage of all births.
Calculation: For England and Wales the Illegitimacy Ratio has been calculated using the numbers of legitimate and illegitimate live births for each RSD published in the Registrar General's Annual Reports. An average of three years of births has been used to minimise the effect of small numbers: the year before the census year, the census year and the year after the census year (although the data stopped being published in this form after 1910, so for 1911 only 1910 is used). For Scotland the number of births for each RD was obtained from the Digitising Scotland database, and these rates are based on 10 year periods (centred on each census) to minimise the effects of small numbers in some RDs. Scotland did not introduce civil registration until 1855, so this rate cannot be calculated for 1851.
See also: Illegitimate birth rate; Legitimate birth rate.
Overview: Illegitimacy was not uncommon in historic Britain, but it underwent a sustained decline over the Victorian era, falling from just under 7 per cent of all births in England, just over 7 in Wales and over 11 per cent in Scotland in the middle of the nineteenth century to around 4 per cent in both England and Wales and 8.4 per cent in Scotland in 1901. As with many demographic characteristics, there were significant geographical variations in illegitimacy. In general AGRICULTURAL areas had higher percentages of illegitimate births, but inspection of the maps shows that this was particularly concentrated in the North-East (Banffshire and Aberdeenshire) and the South-West of Scotland, mid-Wales and Shropshire, Norfolk, the East Riding of Yorkshire, and the North, a phenomenon which has been linked to particular agricultural systems and cultural norms. Illegitimacy ratios were notably low in TRANSPORT areas, while all other types of area witnessed declines in this measure, with particularly rapid and early declines in English and Welsh TEXTILE areas. Particularly high illegitimacy ratios in isolated urban areas may be connected to maternity hospitals and other institutions which catered for unmarried mothers.
The relationship between the Illegitimacy ratio and the Illegitimate birth rate: The Illegitimacy ratio measures illegitimate births as a percentage of all births, and the Illegitimate birth rate measures illegitimate births per 1,000 women of childbearing age. The ratio can therefore be distorted by changes in the number of legitimate births. This can be seen by looking at the English illegitimacy ratios for 1901 and 1911. The number of illegitimate births was actually continuing to decline, but by this stage the number of legitimate births was declining at a similar or faster rate, so the percentage of births which were illegitimate rose. Different levels of legitimate fertility also affected the relationship between the two measures in different places: the illegitimacy ratios in MINING areas seem moderate, but this is because both illegitimate and legitimate birth rates were high. In contrast the illegitimacy ratios in PROFESSIONAL areas seem relatively high towards the end of the period. The reason that the proportion of all births in such areas which were illegitimate was higher than in other types of place by 1911 was partly because legitimate birth rates in this type of area were low. However, the proportion of women in PROFESSIONAL areas who were single was much higher than in other places, so the illegitimate birth rate (the risk that any single woman would have an illegitimate birth) was actually lower than in any other type of place. Despite its deficiencies, the Illegitimacy Ratio uses less data than the Illegitimate Birth Rate and is therefore a more widely calculated measure.
Marriage
Age at Marriage
Definition: This measure, technically called the Singulate Mean Age at Marriage (SMAM), is an indicator of the average age at which men or women married.
Calculation: The census did not record the age at which people married, so this is not a simple average of the actual ages of marriage. Instead, we have used a slightly different calculation which can be derived from census data, called the Singulate Mean Age at Marriage (SMAM). It is the average number of person-years lived in a single (never-married) state among those who marry before age 50. It is calculated from the proportions of men or women single at each age. Although it is not a direct measure of the age at which the men or women in the population actually got married, it will be close to that if marriage patterns were not subject to rapid change, and in the absence of migratory movements which may have swelled or depleted the ranks of unmarried people with individuals who were unlikely to contribute to the marriage market.
Because this indicator uses marital status as reported by individuals on the census forms, it cannot distinguish between those who had gone through a legal or religious ceremony and those who had not. Some couples may have reported themselves as married even if they had not officially wed: the extent and geography of such behaviour are currently unclear although it generally assumed to be rare in Britain in this period. Unmarried women with children may have claimed to have been married or widowed in order to maintain respectability.
See also: Celibacy.
Overview: The age at marriage has been relatively late (in the mid to late 20s) for men and women in Britain since medieval times. In 1851 English men married at age 26.5 on average, with women marrying about a year younger. Marriage in Scotland and Wales was even later, at just over 27.5 for men and 26 for women. After a slight fall between 1851 and 1861, the ages at marriage for both men and women increased, although on slightly different trajectories, and slower in Wales than in England and Scotland, so that men and women were marrying on average at ages 27.6 and 26.3 in England and 28.0 and 25.5 in Wales in 1911, and at ages 28.4 and 26.5 in Scotland in 1901.
There were considerable differences in age at marriage in places dominated by different economic structures. This was particularly the case among women, although increases in marriage age were witnessed everywhere. Marriage age for women was lowest in MINING areas and for men marriage appears to have been very late across the Highlands, and also in pockets of the upland areas of Wales and the North of England.
Comparing the male and female marriage ages for different types of place suggests that between 1861 and 1901 women in PROFESSIONAL areas married at even older ages than men in the same areas. However, this is predominantly an artefact of the way the ages at marriage have been calculated here: the influx of single young women into PROFESSIONAL areas to work as domestic servants increased the number of person years lived as a single person, increasing the age at marriage indicator. The majority of these young women did not stay in these areas and moved elsewhere when they married. There was no corresponding influx of young single men to increase the male SMAM in these areas.
The late age at marriage in Britain was one reason for moderate fertility before the demographic transition: the later marriage occurred the smaller was the proportion of the reproductive years which could be spent having children.
Celibacy
Definition: The number of men or women aged 45-54 who were single (never married), expressed as a percentage of all men or women aged 45-54. Because few people married for the first time after the age of 50, this is taken to represent the percentage of the population who never marry.
Calculation: The measure has used the marital status and age information in the individual level census returns, and has been calculated separately for men and women.
See also: Age at marriage; Sex ratio
Overview:
Between 1851 and 1881 around 10 per cent of men and 12 per cent of women in Britain remained unmarried at the end of their reproductive lives. Over the next two decades these figures started to increase. Celibacy in Scotland was considerably higher than that in England and Wales: nearly one in five women (20 per cent) remained unmarried at age 45-54 across the period, and around 13 per cent of men, rising slightly to 14.5 per cent. At any one time there should be equal numbers of men and women married, but this does not mean that there will necessarily be equal percentages of men and women un-married. The main reason for higher percentages of unmarried women in Victorian England was their lower risk of death. By the age of 45 there were more women in the population than men. Differences in mortality between men and women were similar in Scotland to England and Wales, and higher rates of male emigration from Scotland contribute to the larger difference in celibacy north of the border. Differential migration between men and women also played the major role in driving differential celibacy in smaller geographical units, and by type of place.
Although there were differences in the proportions of men remaining unmarried by type of place, with higher rates in the Scottish Highlands, and parts of Wales and the North of England, these were small compared to the differences in the proportions among women. It was most uncommon for women to remain unmarried in MINING areas throughout the period, while in PROFESSIONAL areas between 20 and 32 per cent of women aged 45-54 never married. These differences were at least partly connected to labour market opportunities and migration among single women. There were few opportunities for single women to work in MINING areas, and therefore little incentive for unmarried women to move to or stay in such areas. In contrast jobs open to single women were more plentiful in PROFESSIONAL areas, leading to high levels of female in-migration and an excess of women in such places.
Mortality and health
Infant mortality rate (IMR)
Definition: The infant mortality rate (IMR) is the number of children who died before their first birthday out of each 1,000 children born.
Calculation: The graph of the national IMR shows annual rates, but for smaller geographic units we show IMRs calculated for the five years leading up to each census to minimise the fluctuations due to small numbers in some areas. To calculate the IMR for our small geographic units, we divided all deaths to infants (i.e. children under a year old) in the five years leading up to each census (e.g. April 1876 to March 1881 for the five years leading up to the 1881 census), by the number of children born in the same period, and multiplied by 1,000. Some of the deaths to infants dying in the early part of the period (e.g. in April 1876) will have been to infants born before the start of the period (e.g. in February 1876), but this is compensated for by the deaths of children born towards the end of the period e.g. in March 1881) who died after the census (e.g. in May 1881). This is the usual method for calculating the infant mortality rate. For England and Wales, the data on infant births and deaths for each RSD were transcribed from the Registrar General's Quarterly Returns of Births, Deaths and Marriages. These data were not produced before 1869, so we have had to assume that infant mortality did not change between 1851 and 1869. For Scotland, the data on infant births and deaths for each RD were obtained from the Digitising Scotland project, https://digitisingscotland.ac.uk/. The annual national figures for Scotland were obtained from the Human Mortality Database, http://www.mortality.org/, and those for England and Wales were transcribed from the Registrar General's Annual Reports.
See also: Early Childhood Mortality Rate (ECMR); Population Density.
Overview: The IMR was around 150 per thousand for England and around 120 per thousand for Scotland across the second half of the nineteenth century. In England, rates were slightly lower in the 1880s, but suffered a resurgence in the 1890s when a series of long, hot summers caused spikes in infant diarrhoeal deaths, particularly in urban areas. Therefore, unlike mortality at older ages of childhood and in adulthood which began to decline from about 1870, there was no sustained decline in national infant mortality rates until the turn of the century. 1911 also saw a particularly hot summer which increased the IMR, and this shows up in the national rates (which are for complete calendar years) but not in our local rates where we have only calculated mortality up to the date of the census which was taken on the 2nd of April, 1911. It is notable that Scotland and Wales started the period with much lower infant mortality. Rates in Wales deteriorated until 1901, due in part to population growth in MINING areas where infant mortality was high, and although mortality did decline in the early twentieth century Wales finished this period with higher rates than in England. Scotland maintained lower infant mortality until 1911, but this was about to change: since the early twentieth century Scotland has had higher infant mortality than England and Wales.
As well as the significant difference between England and Wales and Scotland, there was considerable geographic variation in rates of infant mortality across Britain, with rates below 100 per 1000 in many individual AGRICULTURAL areas and over 200 per thousand in some urban industrial places over the last half of the nineteenth century. Higher urban infant mortality has been attributed to crowded populations living in insanitary conditions, favouring the spread of infectious diseases. English TRANSPORT places had the highest infant mortality at the beginning of the period, with other industrial areas, including English TEXTILE places, also having high rates of infant death (see also Population Density). Mortality was lowest in AGRICULTURAL areas, where a benign disease environment and the chance of spreading infection was low. PROFESSIONAL areas also had (mostly) low mortality rates: in these areas accommodation was well spaced out, facilities were good and housing was often located away from industrial and natural hazards.
The infant mortality rates by type of place show that the resurgence of infant mortality rates in the 1890s was particularly strong in TRANSPORT, MINING and OTHER URBAN places, and that the decline from the turn of the century was less pronounced in MINING areas. The decline was also smaller (or non-existent) in AGRICULTURAL areas where mortality was already low.
Early Childhood Mortality Rate (ECMR)
Definition: The early childhood mortality rate (ECMR) is the number of children who die between their first and fifth birthdays (age 1 to 4 years inclusive), out of every 1,000 children in that age group.
Calculation: The graph of the national ECMRs shows annual rates, calculated by dividing the number of registered deaths (as recorded in the Registrar General's publications for England and Wales, and extracted directly from the digitised registers for Scotland) by the estimated population (derived from censuses). For the smaller areas, data from the Digitising Scotland project (https://digitisingscotland.ac.uk/) allowed us to calculate accurate figures for Scotland, but for England and Wales we were limited to the Registrar General's reports, none of which provide the numbers of deaths to children aged one to four years by Registration Sub-Districts. For England and Wales we therefore estimated the ECMRs for the five years leading up to each census using a statistical model which relates ECMR to infant mortality, industrial structure, and other variables capturing the disease environment and socio-economic conditions (see DOI: 10.4054/DemRes.2017.37.58 for details of this process).
See also: Infant Mortality Rate.
Overview: Unlike the Infant Mortality Rate (IMR), the Early Childhood Mortality Rate (ECMR) - along with mortality in older childhood and adulthood - declined more or less constantly from the 1870s onwards in England, Wales and Scotland. This decline was mainly due to decreasing death rates from a variety of childhood infectious diseases, including scarlet fever, whooping cough and diarrhoea. Rates were initially lower in Wales, and declines were slower, leading to a convergence with England.
As with infant mortality rates, there were large differences in early childhood mortality rates by type of place, with the lowest risks of death in AGRICULTURAL areas, followed by PROFESSIONAL places, and considerably higher risks in the urban industrial heartlands. MINING and TEXTILE areas, although they did not have the highest early childhood mortality, show up strongly in the maps as having high rates because they are geographically concentrated. In general the differences between places reduced as mortality fell, but MINING and OTHER URBAN areas failed to benefit as much as other types of places did from the improvements in child health over this period.
Doctors
Definition: The number of doctors per 10,000 people.
Calculation: This measure has been based on the occupations individual people recorded on the census forms. Doctors include all those reporting themselves to be a doctor, physician, surgeon, registered practitioner, etc. The number of doctors in each area has been divided by the population in that area and multiplied by 10,000 to get a rate per 10,000 people.
See also: Infant Mortality Rate; Early Childhood Mortality Rate.
Overview: The number of doctors per 10,000 people can be interpreted as an indicator of health service provision. It does not include other health professionals such as nurses, midwives, health visitors and so on, as it is not straightforward to identify these in the census. It is important to remember that during this period there was no free health care. Doctors were all private practitioners, although some may have been paid by the Poor Law to provide care for paupers, and others may have charged lower fees for needy cases. It is also the case that before the development of powerful drugs such as antibiotics, medical care was much less effective than it is today. Before the widespread acceptance of germ theory and the antiseptic revolution, a doctor's visit may even have increased the chance of illness through the transfer of infection from another patient.
Overall, the number of doctors per 10,000 people increased between the early part of the period and the later part - a rise which occurred earlier in England and Wales (although Wales always had lower numbers of doctors per patient) than it did in Scotland. The slight dip in 1861 in England may be a result of the 1858 Medical Act which required all medical practitioners to register with the newly established General Medical Council: this may have led to a reduction in the number of unqualified persons reporting themselves as doctors, however this does not appear to have had much effect in Wales or Scotland.
Given that the majority of doctors relied on private practice, it is unsurprising that PROFESSIONAL areas were considerably better served with doctors than other types of place throughout the period: doctors were more likely to have set up their practices among clientele who could afford their services. Industrial areas, particularly TEXTILE, MINING and OTHER URBAN places had fewer doctors per 10,000 people than other types of place throughout the period.
Focussing in on London, there was considerable inequality in the numbers of doctors per 10,000 people, with better medical provision in West London and suburban areas. It is important to remember that this indicator reflects where doctors were living, rather than where they practised. In many cases these will have been the same: it was common during the nineteenth century for a GP to have his (or her, but female doctors were extremely rare) surgery at his own home. However, hospital and poor law doctors may well have travelled from a salubrious suburb to provide care for the inhabitants of an inner city area, thus these spatial differentials in London and other cities may be exaggerated by commuting practices.
Households
Lone parent households
Definition: The number of households containing a lone-parent family (at least one child under the age of 15 with only one parent present), expressed as a percentage of all households.
Calculation: Lone parent families are defined as one parent (married, widowed or single) living with at least one unmarried child aged under 15 and without any other kin. Because the census recorded each person where they happened to be on census night, rather than where they usually lived, it is impossible to tell if an absent husband or wife of a married parent was permanently or temporarily absent from the household. In the Victorian censuses, a household was not necessarily just a family: it may have included others living in the dwelling, such as boarders, servants, or more distant relatives. The census forms asked each individual to identify their relationship to the head of the household, and it is this variable which is used to identify family relationships. It is relatively easy to identify the spouse and children of the head of household, but more difficult to identify family groups which do not include the head. As a result this variable may undercount lone-parent families if a link between a parent and a child cannot be made, but overcount them when a parent-child link can be made but the link between parents is missed. The particularly low percentages of lone parent families in Oxfordshire and Berkshire in 1851 are likely to be connected to transcription issues making it difficult to make parent-child links. There are also some areas of Scotland in 1861 where relationship to head was poorly recorded, which affects this variable.
See also: Illegitimate birth rate; Illegitimacy ratio
Overview: The percentage of households containing a lone-parent family declined steadily from around 1870. A considerable amount of this decline is likely to be due to the decrease in adult mortality which started in the 1870s, although the fact that the decline was sharper in Scotland despite very similar reductions in mortality indicates that other factors were also important. Most instances of family dissolution in the nineteenth century were caused by the death of either the husband or the wife - divorce was difficult, expensive and out of reach of the majority of the population. However, 'informal' marriages, more common in Scotland, may have been easier to dissolve. As today, the majority of lone-parent families were headed by a mother rather than a father. Partly this was because men tended to die before women: not only was male mortality higher at each age, but husbands were on average a little older than their wives. However, it is also the case that widowed men were more likely to get re-married than widowed women, or for their children to be sent to live with another family member (the census data do not allow us to routinely distinguish couples who have re-married from couples on their first marriage). Some lone-parent families may have been composed of unmarried mothers and children, but while illegitimacy was not uncommon in this era it is difficult to identify illegitimate children in the census, even those living with their mother, so lone-parent families of this type are likely to be undercounted in these data. It is possible that some unmarried mothers reported themselves as married in order to preserve their respectability. It is noticeable that the patterns of lone-parent families in different types of place do not correspond with illegitimate birth rates, suggesting that unmarried mothers with their children do not form a major component of lone-parent families.
Declines in lone-parent households in every type of place reflect the widespread nature of the declines in adult mortality. However, the somewhat higher levels of such households in TRANSPORT areas probably reflect the differing likelihood of fathers to have been temporarily working elsewhere. The temporary absence of sailors, drivers, carters etc. can explain the particularly high prevalence of lone-parent households in the fishing communities in the North West, the South West, and Wales. AGRICULTURAL areas had low levels of lone-parent households, and the fact that the census was deliberately held in the spring when seasonal agricultural labour migration was low might help explain this. However adult mortality was also lower in healthy rural areas than in towns and this will also have contributed to the lower prevalence of lone-parent households.
Single person households
Definition: Households containing only one person, expressed as a percentage of all households.
Calculation: The number of households containing only one person is divided by the total number of households and multiplied by 100. It might seem easy to define a household, but for the nineteenth century it is actually quite problematic. This is because families often rented out part of their homes under a variety of arrangements: from boarders who paid rent, ate with the family and may even have shared a bedroom with them, to lodgers who rented a separate floor or apartment. Until the end of the nineteenth century, the census instructions were not always clear about how to treat boarders and lodgers, let alone the grey areas in between (such as someone renting a room and using the kitchen). Lodgers were supposed to be recorded in households of their own. In some years census instructions to householders and enumerators made this more likely to have happened, and consequently the percentage of households containing only one person was higher, and the percentage containing boarders or more distant relatives (who may have also paid rent) was lower.
See also: Households with boarders; Households with kin; Elderly per working age adults
Overview:
The fluctuations in the percentage of single-person households before 1891 can probably be attributed to the ambiguities in the definition of household (see Calculation). The percentage of households containing only one person was therefore probably rather stable over time in this time period, at 5 to 6 per cent in England and Wales and 8 per cent in Scotland (in contrast, 17 per cent of households contained only one person in 1971 and in 2016 this figure had risen to 28 per cent). As today, single person households were mainly made up of two demographic groups: the elderly (particularly widows and widowers) and young adults who had not yet entered a relationship. The latter were also likely to be boarders or lodgers and it is probable that the fluctuations in single-person households were mainly due to treatment of the household position of younger adults.
Although the overall trend was probably actually rather flat, the proportion of households containing only one person varied considerably geographically and by type of place. Single person households were particularly rare in industrial areas; especially those dominated by mining, metal work, and, in England, textiles. In contrast, people in AGRICULTURAL and PROFESSIONAL places were more likely to have lived alone. There are several factors which may have contributed to these geographic differences: the growth of industry means that there was considerable migration from agricultural areas to take up industrial jobs. This kept the proportion of elderly people (and thus potential single-person households) in industrial populations low. The other side of this coin is the movement of young adults away from the countryside, where the elderly therefore formed a larger share of the population. The high proportions of single-person households in PROFESSIONAL areas were, however, largely due to the many, probably unmarried, young men who lived in single-person lodger households. In 1861 both England and Wales showed higher proportions of single-person households than surrounding census years, and a similar drop in the proportions of households with kin (this is less easy to spot in the graphs as the overall proportions with kin are higher). It is possible that this is the result of the wording of census instructions. Similarly in Scotland fluctuations in the proportions of single-person households, those with kin and those who were boarders between 1891 and 1901 are likely to be connected to wording issues in the census instructions: in 1891 people were more likely to have been recorded in a household of their own than as a relative or boarder, but the opposite was true in 1901. It is not surprising that these fluctuations were not synchronous as the censuses in Scotland and in England and Wales were conducted independently and the instructions provided on the household schedules and given to enumerators were not always identical north and south of the Scottish-English border.
Households with boarders
Definition: Households containing at least one boarder, expressed as a percentage of all households.
Calculation: Boarders were defined as people renting a room or bed in someone else's house, and taking meals with the householder's family. They can be identified by 'boarder' being written in the 'relationship to household head' column on the census form. Lodgers, who rented a separate space from another household and did not share meals, were supposed to fill out a separate census form as their own household, but this did not always happen. Some people are also identified as 'lodger' in the 'relationship to household head' column and here we have treated lodgers identified in this way as boarders. A household has been classed as containing boarders if at least one person was identified as a boarder (or lodger), and the number of households with boarders has been divided by the total number of households and multiplied by 100. There was some fluctuation in the percentage of households with boarders because of confusion about whether and when a boarder/lodger should fill out a separate household schedule, as the census instructions regarding this were not always clear. There was also potential confusion between boarders and relatives, as some relatives may have paid rent and qualified as both, but only one relationship could be recorded. There are also some areas of Scotland in 1861 where relationship to head was poorly recorded, which affects this variable.
See also: Households with kin; Single-person households
Overview: 11-12 per cent of households in England and Wales, and closer to 15 per cent of those in Scotland, contained boarders (or lodgers) in each census year from 1851 to 1911, with exceptions possibly indicating confusion about whether or not sub-letters should fill in a separate census form and be treated as a different household. Although there was little unambiguous change over time in this period, there was considerable geographical variation. The maps show that in AGRICULTURAL areas around 9 or 10 per cent of households had boarders, while in MINING areas the figure was considerably higher. In many districts of the South Wales coal field, for example, over 18 per cent of households contained at least one boarder. Mining was a strongly growing industrial sector at this time, with an influx of young men migrating to work there, so it is possible that high proportions of boarders reflected the failure of the housing stock in South Wales to keep up with demand. In contrast, AGRICULTURAL areas were characterised by out-migration, so pressure on housing was likely to have been lower, but again there was regional variation: the predominantly agricultural areas of South East England in Sussex and Kent show relatively high proportions of households with boarders.
Households with kin
Definition: Households containing people related to the head other than his/her immediate family, expressed as a percentage of all households. These could be thought of as extended families.
Calculation: The head's immediate family has been defined as either his wife (or her husband) and his or her unmarried children; or, if he or she is unmarried, his or her parents (and siblings too, but only if at least one parent is present). Any other people whose relationship to head suggests a family relationship (e.g. mother or mother-in-law of a married head, grand-child, niece or nephew) have been treated as relatives or kin. Any household with at least one person defined this way has been treated as a household with kin. The number of households with kin has been divided by the total number of households and multiplied by 100.
See also: Households with boarders; Single-person households; Lone-parent households.
Overview: In most of the census years around 20 per cent of households in England and Wales contained kin (including situations where parents and married children lived together, and grandchildren lived with grandparents), with slightly higher levels in Scotland than in England and Wales. Although elderly people did not routinely live with their married children (as discussed in the section on single-person households many ended up living alone), these types of relationship were still the most common among households with kin.
There was rather little variation in the percentage of households with kin by type of place, and some convergence over time. However the maps indicate a strong South-East to North-West gradient, with lower levels in the South-East of England and the highest levels in the Highlands of Scotland. The higher levels in the rural areas of Scotland were to some extent balanced by lower levels in the industrial central belt.
Households with live-in servants
Definition: Households which had at least one live-in servant (excluding those specifically designated as farm servants), expressed as a percentage of all households.
Calculation: This indicator has been calculated by classing each household where there was at least one person whose relationship to the head of household was given as 'servant' as a servant-keeping household. The number of servant-keeping households was then divided by the total number of households and multiplied by 100. There are also some areas of Scotland in 1861 where relationship to head was poorly recorded, which affects this variable.
See also: Social class; RG's class; Domestic servants (women); Single women working.
Overview: During the pre-industrial and industrialising periods of British history, it was very common for young people to spend a period of time as a live-in servant in another family's household. This usually occurred between the late teens and mid-twenties, and was particularly common among women, allowing them to save up money which would allow them to contribute towards the setting up of an independent household when they married. This institution of live-in service was in decline, however, from at least the mid-nineteenth century. In both England and Scotland the percentage of households which had at least one live-in servant declined from about 15 per cent in 1851 to just under 10 per cent in 1911. The percentages in Wales were rather higher (probably due to the type of farming which relied more on live-in farm servants than on agricultural labourers who lived off site) but declined at a similar rate to England.
Only the better-off sections of society, of course, could afford to keep a permanent live-in servant purely to look after the household, although many farming households also employed servants whose duties probably combined household and agricultural work. The maps show servant-keeping to be high in the hill-farming regions of Wales and the North of England and Aberdeenshire and Banffshire where live-stock farming was common. Comparatively high levels of live-in servant keeping can be seen in the suburbanising ring around London, but these PROFESSIONAL places, although they had far higher levels of servant-keeping in each year, also witnessed the fastest decline in the practice.
It should be remembered that this variable only measures live-in service: some servants may have lived elsewhere and gone in to work each day, or when needed.
Age structure
Dependency ratios
Definition: The number of dependents (children aged less than 14; elderly aged 65 and over; or both) per 100 working-age people (aged 14-64).
Calculation: Everyone was asked to record their age in the census, and we have counted the numbers of people in different age groups: children (those less than 14 years), working-age (those 14-64 years), and elderly (age 65 and over). The dependency ratio has been calculated by dividing the number of children and elderly (combined) by the number of working-age people and multiplying by 100. The child dependency ratio divides just the number of children by the number of working-age people, multiplying by 100; and the old age dependency ratio divides the number of elderly by the number of working-age people, multiplying by 100. We have identified dependent children as those under the age of 14, because many children older than this were earning money (see Children's work and schooling). Of course, some younger children were also earning money - particularly at the beginning of the period - and many older children were not. Similarly, many people carried on working past the age of 65, particularly before old age pensions were introduced in 1908 (even then, these were only available to those over the age of 70, and did not cover everyone). Men would have stopped working at various ages, depending on their health and resources, and married women of all ages were unlikely to have earned money outside the house although they would have been working hard running the household - important labour which, although unpaid, contributed enormously to the household economy. These factors mean that these dependency measures do not measure strict economic dependency, although they can be interpreted as measuring the potential dependency burden.
See also: Children's work and schooling; Women's work; Fertility
Overview: Between 1851 and 1881 there were between 60 and 65 dependents (children and those aged over 65) for every 100 working-age people (aged 14-64), but this began to decline after 1881 and was nearing 50 by the end of the period. Examination of the child and old age dependency ratios separately shows that this decline was almost entirely due to a decline in the number of children per worker, which can be attributed to fertility decline. Towards the end of the period the old age dependency ratio began to creep up as mortality decline spread to those over 65, but this effect was still tiny in comparison to that of declining fertility. Throughout the period there were far more child dependents than elderly, reflecting a roughly pyramidal age structure created by relatively high fertility and mortality.
Because child dependency dominated overall dependency ratios, and child dependency was mainly affected by fertility, spatial and temporal patterns in overall and child dependency were very similar to spatial and temporal patterns in fertility. Like fertility, therefore, dependency ratios were particularly high in MINING areas and low in PROFESSIONAL places. Different spatial patterns in the proportion of elderly people also had an effect, and higher proportions of elderly increased the dependency ratio in AGRICULTURAL areas. It must be remembered that these ratios were not simply the product of fertility (affecting numbers of children) and mortality (primarily affecting the elderly) but also of the numbers of working-age people. Locally and regionally, numbers of people in this age group could vary substantially due to in- or out-migration. High levels of out-migration of young adults meant that the working-age group was small in comparison to the elderly in AGRICULTURAL areas. Substantial numbers of temporary in-migrants, such as servants, many of whom would not have settled permanently in the area, will have contributed to lower dependency ratios: this phenomenon can be seen in the West End of London. In other places dependency ratios may have been a function of the history of migration over the previous 50-100 years: this can be seen in many industrial areas (especially MINING and English TEXTILE places) where low numbers of the elderly relative to working-age people may have been because not all the migrants who settled in these areas had yet had time to grow old. In MINING areas the low old age dependency ratio is more than counteracted by high child dependency, but in English TEXTILE areas these forces were working in tandem by the end of the nineteenth century.
Average age
Definition: The mean age of the population in the area.
Calculation: The average age of the population has been calculated using 'age last birthday' (ie whole numbers, with 0 for infants less than one year) as provided by each individual in the census enumerators' books. The age of every person who provided a valid age is added up, and the total divided by the number of people who gave a valid age. Average age has been calculated for the entire population, and for women and men separately.
See also: Dependency ratio, Child dependency ratio, Old age dependency ratio, Fertility, Sex ratio
Overview: Average age is a summary measure of the age structure of the population. It is affected by recent fertility (affecting the proportion of children in the population), mortality (depleting the population at various ages), and age specific patterns of migration (particularly among young adults). Between 1851 and 1881 the average age in Britain was just under 26 years, and the sharp increase that followed was mainly due to the decline in fertility which started after 1881, reducing the number of children in relation to the rest of the population. Mortality decline also started around this period, but in the nineteenth century this was concentrated among children and younger adults which would have increased the proportion of young people in the population, exerting downward pressure on the average age. However persistently lower mortality among women than men is responsible for the higher average age of women across the period.
There were large regional variations in average age, with MINING areas having the lowest average age and PROFESSIONAL areas the highest. This was partly due to differences in fertility rates, with the higher numbers of children born in MINING districts leading to younger averages, and delayed fertility declines in such places contributed to increasing divergence with the average age in PROFESSIONAL districts over time. However geographical differences were also affected by migration patterns. Outmigration of young adults (both men and women) from AGRICULTURAL areas led to increasingly large proportions of the population in the older age groups. The lack of young adults also depressed the numbers of children born, even though those who stayed did not have particularly low fertility; together these two factors led to high average ages in AGRICULTURAL areas, particularly the Scottish highlands. In PROFESSIONAL areas it was in-migration of young, single adults which contributed to high average ages. As few of these migrants had children, PROFESSIONAL areas contained low proportions of children, increasing the average age of their populations.
In almost all types of place, women were on average older than men, and differences in the average age between genders in different types of place were primarily due to differential migration by gender. This age gap was largest in PROFESSIONAL areas, which had many employment opportunities for women and were therefore particularly attractive places for adult females to move to. MINING areas, in contrast, had few job openings for women, but many for men. The male population in these areas therefore contained more adults in relation to children than did the female population, increasing the average age for men. By the end of the period, men were on average older than women in both English and Welsh MINING districts.
Migration
Life-time migration
Definition: This measure gives the number of people in each of seven life-time migration groups expressed as a percentage of the population. Life-time migration measures the distance a person has moved from the place they were born to where they were living on a particular census day. It does not measure any intervening moves, just the distance from birthplace to current residence. In PopulationsPast three of the groups used are for those both born and resident in England, both born and resident in Wales, or both born and resident in Scotland; they identify those living less than 10km, 10-49km or 50km or more from their birthplace. The remaining four groups identify those born in either of the 'other GB' nations that they were not living in (ie for those living in England, people born in Wales or Scotland), those born in Ireland, or those born in a foreign country.
Calculation: Percentages have been calculated using the information on birth place reported in the individual level census returns. People both born and living in England and Wales, and people both born and living in Scotland, were asked to report their parish and county of birth. Each place of birth has been allocated a grid reference, as has each place of residence, and the distance migrated is calculated as a straight line between the two. Residents in England and Wales who were born in Scotland, and vice versa, as well as those born in Ireland or a foreign country were only required to give their country of birth, so it is not possible to calculate distance migrated and they have been categorised by their place of birth instead (NB Ireland was not divided into the Republic of Ireland and Northern Ireland at this time; the whole island of Ireland was part of the United Kingdom of Great Britain and Ireland). Although residents in England who were born in Wales and vice versa gave their parish of birth, we have not used the calculated migration distances, so as to allow consistency over the English-Welsh and English-Scottish borders. Percentages in different categories do not add up to 100 because some birthplaces have proved difficult to decipher or to accurately allocate to a precise location, an issue which is more prominent in particular years and in some types of place in Scotland.
See also: Sex ratio in the working ages
Overview: Around 60 per cent of the British population (just over for England and just under for Scotland) were still living within 10km of their place of birth at each census. However quite a large proportion of the population were children (see child dependency ratio) who were less likely to have moved, partly because they had not lived as long and partly because they had not yet reached the most common age to move – young adulthood. Among the adult population, however, it was common for people to be living some distance away from their place of birth. Over time those who had moved more than 10km were increasingly likely to have moved more than 50km. Among those born and remaining in either England or Scotland, women were a little more likely to have migrated than men, and travelled further when they did so. Migration between the three countries of England, Scotland and Wales was also increasing, and it is important to remember that the relative size of the receiving population, as well as the numbers moving, affects these figures. A relatively large proportion of the Welsh population – by 1911 nearly 20 per cent of men - had been born in England. In contrast less than 1 per cent of the English population had been born in Wales. As proportions of the receiving population this is a big difference, but the actual numbers of migrants moving from England to Wales and from Wales to England were not dissimilar. Wales's smaller population means that as a proportion of the sending population, Wales sent more migrants to England than vice versa. The high proportion of English migrants in Wales is to some extent a function of Wales's small population, but the growing coal industry also attracted English men, and the fact that there was a long border meant that it was easy to be counted as a migrant in either direction with just a relatively short move.
Around 60 per cent of the British population (just over for England and just under for Scotland) were still living within 10km of their place of birth at each census. However quite a large proportion of the population were children (see child dependency ratio) who were less likely to have moved, partly because they had not lived as long and partly because they had not yet reached the most common age to move – young adulthood. Among the adult population, however, it was common for people to be living some distance away from their place of birth. Over time those who had moved more than 10km were increasingly likely to have moved more than 50km. Among those born and remaining in either England or Scotland, women were a little more likely to have migrated than men, and travelled further when they did so. Migration between the three countries of England, Scotland and Wales was also increasing, and it is important to remember that the relative size of the receiving population, as well as the numbers moving, affects these figures. A relatively large proportion of the Welsh population – by 1911 nearly 20 per cent of men - had been born in England. In contrast less than 1 per cent of the English population had been born in Wales. As proportions of the receiving population this is a big difference, but the actual numbers of migrants moving from England to Wales and from Wales to England were not dissimilar. Wales's smaller population means that as a proportion of the sending population, Wales sent more migrants to England than vice versa. The high proportion of English migrants in Wales is to some extent a function of Wales's small population, but the growing coal industry also attracted English men, and the fact that there was a long border meant that it was easy to be counted as a migrant in either direction with just a relatively short move.
Different types of place had quite different in-migration patterns. The TEXTILE areas had relatively few in-migrants in the 1851-1911 period – over 70 per cent of inhabitants of English TEXTILE areas were still living within 10km of their place of birth. In contrast this figure was lowest in PROFESSIONAL areas where women were more likely than men to be living over 10km and particularly over 50km from their place of birth. AGRICULTURAL places also saw an increase in the proportions of in-migrants within their populations, which may appear surprising, as much movement during this time was from rural to urban areas. It seems that this did not mean that rural areas were only inhabited by those 'left behind', and there was considerable movement to or between, as well as from, rural areas. OTHER URBAN and TRANSPORT areas, in contrast, appear to have become more local, with increasing proportions of their populations living within 10km of their birth. This may be due to the strong role of birth rates in increasing the population of such areas, and this is particularly visible when looking at the decline in the proportion of the population born in Ireland in English TRANSPORT and Scottish OTHER URBAN areas: if Irish migrants had children in England or Wales, those children will have been identified in the census as English- or Welsh-born not Irish- or Scottish-born. MINING areas show an uneven pattern, with the main coalfields exhibiting different histories of migration. Irish-born people - particularly men - were very common in the Scottish coal-fields in the mid-nineteenth century, although they declined over time. The South Wales and Durham/Northumberland coalfields also witnessed considerable in-migration which did not seem to be taking place in the Derbyshire-Nottinghamshire/Yorkshire coalfield in the second half of the 19th century.
In MINING and OTHER URBAN areas men were more likely than women to have been living 50km or more from their place of birth, suggesting that industrial job opportunities were a particular pull for male migrants. Nevertheless, the proportions of men and women in the different migration categories in a place were usually quite similar, particularly in Scotland, suggesting that some people may have migrated as a couple or with their family, or that some women migrated to industrial areas to join their husband or to marry.
Irish migrants to England and Wales were often restricted to manual jobs; many worked as labourers in the docks or as navvies constructing railways. English and Welsh TRANSPORT areas, particularly those with docks, always had considerably higher percentages of Irish-born people than other areas, especially in the years immediately after the potato famine. In London, the East End dock districts were home to many Irish people: in 1851 over a quarter of the population of the Registration Sub-District of Aldgate had been born in Ireland. However the Liverpool docks were even more heavily Irish, probably because many Irish people sailed from Ireland into Liverpool. In 1851 nearly half (47 per cent) of people living in the Registration Sub-District of Howard Street in Liverpool had been born in Ireland. Other Irish migrants found work in the army, and this can explain high percentages of Irish-born in the Aldershot (Hampshire) area, which was the main base of the British Army. Irish migrants to Scotland were observed in a greater variety of places, although they were concentrated in Ayrshire and Wigtownshire (both easily accessible from the north of Ireland) and the central belt, they were unlikely to live in AGRICULTURAL or PROFESSIONAL areas.
Migrants between England and Scotland were particularly concentrated close to the border between the two countries and therefore might not actually have moved very far. They were also more likely to be living in PROFESSIONAL and SEMI-PROFESSIONAL areas.
Foreign born people formed an increasing percentage of PROFESSIONAL areas over time, particularly those in and around London. However they were also quite common in TRANSPORT areas, especially those on the South coast. They formed the smallest proportions of the population in TEXTILE, MINING and AGRICULTURAL areas.
Sex ratio in the working ages
Definition: The number of working-age men (14-64 years) for every 100 working-age women (age 14-64 years).
Calculation: The numbers of men and women aged from 14 to 64 years have been calculated using the information on age and sex given in the census for each person. The number of men has been divided by the number of women and multiplied by 100.
See also: Women's work, Social class, Life-time migration
Overview: In most populations there are between 104 and 107 male babies born for every 100 female babies. Males, however, have a higher risk of death than females at almost every age, particularly during infancy and childhood. Therefore by adulthood most populations have a more even number of men and women, or an excess of women. In England there were about 92 men aged 14-64 per 100 women in each of the census years from 1851 to 1911. Wales had more men per woman, with roughly even numbers in 1851, rising to around 107 men per 100 women in 1911, while in Scotland there were fewer (85, rising to nearly 93 by 1901). Variations in the sex ratio from place to place, however, were not because sex ratios at birth or differential mortality varied, but because of different levels of migration among men and women. The sex ratio in the working-age group is therefore of considerable interest as an indicator of migration, and can add information about out-migration which the measures of life-time migration based on birth place cannot easily provide.
Where the sex ratio within a population was higher than 100, there were more men than women, and this could be due to either in-migration of men or out-migration of women. MINING areas in the nineteenth century tended to have high sex ratios, as did areas with army and naval bases, such as Aldershot in Hampshire and Tilbury in Essex, suggesting high levels of male in-migration. However, there may also have been significant female out-migration from these areas, particularly MINING areas where job opportunities for women were scarce. Where the sex ratio was lower than 100, there were more women than men. Low sex ratios in PROFESSIONAL areas were likely to have been caused by greater in-migration of young women to work as servants (see Life-time migration). The low sex ratios in West Wales were, however, probably related to higher levels of male migration away from the area. It follows from what has been said that differential migration is strongly linked to particular industrial and occupational structures. It is important to realise that the sex ratio can only indicate where there were differences in migration between men and women. In places where similar numbers of men and women migrated in or out, the sex ratio for that place would not appear unusual, even if the number of migrants was very large. The high and increasing sex ratio in Wales is likely to be linked to the growth of the South Wales mining industry and consequent male dominated in-migration. The low sex ratio in Scotland in the middle of the nineteenth century suggests that migration out of the country was male-dominated. Other sources indicate that migration had not diminished by 1901, and was still higher than in England and Wales. The rise in the sex ratio is thus likely to have been caused by a trend towards more even rates of migration among men and women.
Socio-economic status & Social class
Socio-economic status (SES)
Definition: This definition of socio-economic status (SES), based on HISCLASS, provides the number of men aged 14-64 years in each of five socio-economic status groups, expressed as a percentage of all men aged 14-64 years.
Calculation: HISCLASS is an international historical socio-economic status (SES) scheme, designed to allow comparisons across different periods, countries and languages (http://www.hisma.org/HISMA/HISCLASS.html). It allocates each occupational title to one of 12 classes, but here we have summarised those into just five larger groups. These five socio-economic groups are: 1 (HISCLASS 1 & 2): high skilled non-manual workers such as higher managers and professionals; 2 (HISCLASS 3-6): lower skilled non-manual workers such as clerical and sales personnel; 3 (HISCLASS 7-8): higher skilled manual workers such as plasterers, blacksmiths, farmers, and fishermen; 4 (HISCLASS 9-10): lower skilled manual workers including miners and many factory workers; and 5 (HISCLASS 11-12): unskilled manual workers including farm labourers and general labourers. The number of men aged 14-64 in each group has been counted, divided by the total number of men aged 14-64 who gave an occupation, and multiplied by 100.
It is important to bear in mind that this definition of socio-economic status is unlikely to match exactly to status or consumption hierarchies, and that the levels of 'skill' embedded in the categorisation may be challenged.
Please note: The scales on the maps for each SES group are different.
See also: Social class - RG; Type of place, Women's work.
Overview: Industrial and occupational change over this period is evident in the increasing percentages of men occupied in non-manual work (social classes 1 and 2), although SES:1 still made up only a very small percentage of the total. There was also a rise in lower skilled manual workers (SES: 4) over time. These increases were at the expense of a proportionate decrease in unskilled labourers, many of whom worked in agriculture. Agricultural labourers decreased in absolute terms too, declining by about a third between 1851 and 1911. Agricultural mechanisation and increasing efficiency in farming meant that at least as much food could be produced with less and less labour, and men who would previously have been agricultural labourers found more lucrative work in the manufacturing and tertiary sectors. This labour market shift is reflected in rural to urban migration flows as people moved to areas with increasing job opportunities.
The five SES groups were not evenly distributed across the different types of place. PROFESSIONAL places had significantly higher proportions of men employed in non-manual occupations, although these proportions were not increasing as fast as in other types of place. The growth in non-manual classes was particularly strong in London and its surroundings, although there was some retreat of the most privileged away from the centre to outer and suburban districts. Skilled non-manual workers (SES:2), such as clerks and sales workers, increased everywhere, but cities such as London, Manchester and Birmingham exhibited particularly marked growth. SES:3 includes farmers, as well as a variety of other skilled workers, and the westerly areas of England and Wales as well as much of the Scottish Highlands, where agriculture was dominated by small family farms, showed higher than average concentrations of this group. However this was also true of places with certain industries such as shoe-making, and the geographic distribution of SES:3 changed little over the time period. MINING and TEXTILE areas had particularly high proportions of semi-skilled manual workers (SES:4), which is not surprising given that most miners and textile workers were placed in this class. Growth in the proportion of men in SES:4 was stronger in MINING areas than in TEXTILE areas, reflecting the growth of the mining industry over this period. AGRICULTURAL areas, particularly those in the south east of the country, had high but declining proportions of unskilled manual labourers. This group contains both agricultural labourers and general labourers and the decline in numbers amongst the former group was probably the main cause of the geographic variations in the proportion of SES:5 men.
Social class - RG
Definition: The social class variables given here provide the number of men aged 15-64 years in each social class (as defined by the Registrar General in 1911) expressed as a percentage of all men aged 15-64 years.
Calculation: This classification was designed by the Registrar General (RG) of England and Wales in 1911. It is based on occupation, and allocates each occupational title to one of five RG's classes, while also singling out three groups of occupations for special treatment. These three special groups are not included in the five RG's classes. The RG's classes are: I: professional and managerial (e.g. doctor, lawyer, accountant); II: Skilled non-manual/intermediate (e.g. farmer, dealer); III: Skilled manual (e.g. plasterer, blacksmith, electrician); IV: Semi-skilled manual (e.g. machinist, postman, barman); V: Unskilled manual (e.g. labourer, watchman). The three special occupational groups are: VI: Textile workers; VII: Miners; and VIII: Agricultural labourers. The number of men aged 14-64 in each group has been counted, divided by the total number of men aged 14-64 who gave an occupation, and multiplied by 100.
It is important to bear in mind that this definition of class is unlikely to match exactly to status or consumption hierarchies, and that the levels of 'skill' embedded in the categorisation may be challenged.
Although this classification has many similarities with Socio-economic status also provided here, it also has important differences. The main difference is the separation of the three 'special' occupational groups into separate classes. Another notable difference is that farmers are placed in RG's class II, whereas they fall in SES:3. The RG's classification is useful for comparison with the work of other people who have previously carried out research on late nineteenth- and early twentieth-century England and Wales, as they have mostly used this scheme. However, the RG's class scheme does not allow easy comparison with work undertaken on other countries or other times, and for this reason we also show the more widely used Socio-economic status based on HISCLASS.
Please note: The scales on the maps for each class are different.
See also: Socio-economic status; Type of place, Women's work.
Overview: Industrial and occupational change over the 1851-1911 period is evident in the increasing proportion of men designated as belonging to the highest social class (social class I). However, there was also a rise in social class IV over time, and a growth in the proportion of men employed as miners, particularly evident in Wales. The largest decrease was in the proportion of men employed as agricultural labourers, and these workers decreased in absolute terms too: the number of agricultural labourers declined by about a third between 1851 and 1911. Agricultural mechanisation and increasing efficiency in farming meant that at least as much food was able to be produced with less and less labour, and men who would previously have been employed as agricultural labourers found more lucrative work in the manufacturing and tertiary sectors.
The different social classes were not evenly distributed across the different types of place. Unsurprisingly, textile workers were concentrated in TEXTILE districts, miners in MINING districts, and agricultural labourers in AGRICULTURAL districts. PROFESSIONAL and SEMI-PROFESSIONAL places had significantly higher proportions of men allocated to social class I, although this proportion was not increasing as fast as in other types of place. Along with MINING areas, OTHER URBAN areas had low proportions of the highest social classes. However, the highest proportions of social class V, the lowest and least skilled class, were found in TRANSPORT areas which were characterised by insecure manual work loading, un-loading and guarding goods.
Women's work
Married women working
Definition: The number of married women aged 15 or over recorded as having an occupation (other than housewife or household duties), expressed as a percentage of all married women aged 15 or over.
Calculation: The percentage of married women working has been calculated using the marital status, age, sex, and occupation fields in the individual level census returns. The number of women aged 15 or over reported to be married and in employment was divided by the number of all married women aged 15 or over and the result multiplied by 100.
See also: Single women working; Widowed women working; Domestic servants; Textile workers; Socio-economic status; Social class - RG
Overview: In England the propensity of married women to record an occupation on census night halved between 1851 (20 per cent) and 1901 (9 per cent), with the biggest drop recorded between the 1881 and 1891 censuses. The drop in Scotland started from lower levels and exhibiting a more gradual change. To some extent changes in this variable (and fluctuation in Wales) may be affected by the way that the occupation question was asked in the different censuses, and the particular instructions which were given regarding married women. For example, between 1851 and 1881 respondents in England and Wales were instructed that the female relatives of farmers or lodging house keepers were to be recorded as occupied, as 'farmer's wife' or 'lodging house keeper's wife'. This instruction was dropped in 1891 and this might contribute to the sudden fall in married women's work in this year.
However, inspection of the maps shows that married women's work was highly spatially concentrated, and not limited to areas with significant numbers of farmers' and lodging house keepers' wives. Between the 1850s and 1880s there were significant employment opportunities for married women in textile manufacture in Lancashire and West Yorkshire; the straw plaiting industry in Bedfordshire and Essex; glove making and other sewing in Worcestershire; pottery in Stoke on Trent; and lace-making in Devon and in Nottinghamshire/Leicestershire. By the end of the century these enclaves had either disappeared or shrunk considerably.
This picture of shrinking work opportunities for married women is confirmed by the graph of percentages of married women working in the different types of place. Opportunities for paid work for married women were always considerably higher in TEXTILE areas (particularly those in England), and lowest in MINING areas, but they reduced everywhere between 1851 and 1901.
The contraction in employment opportunities for married women has been attributed to the rise of the 'male breadwinner ethic' and the 'cult of domesticity' which identified the home as the proper place for a married woman. Within this culture, paid work in most areas became restricted to only the poorest and most desperate of married women. These cultural factors might also have made male heads increasingly reluctant to record occupations for their wives, but the simultaneous decrease in job opportunities for widowed women suggests that the downturn was a real phenomenon, rather than a cultural artefact. It is also important to note that the census was supposed to record regular, paid occupations, and it is therefore likely to have excluded a variety of seasonal and ad hoc opportunities for women to earn money, as well as unpaid labour.
Single women working
Definition: The number of single women aged 15 or over recorded as having an occupation (other than housewife or household duties), expressed as a percentage of all single women aged 15 or over.
Calculation: The percentage of single women working has been calculated using the marital status, age, sex, and occupation fields in the individual level census returns. The number of women aged 15 or over reported to be unmarried and in employment was divided by the number of all unmarried women aged 15 or over and the result multiplied by 100.
See also: Married women working; Widowed women working; Domestic servants; Textile workers; Socio-economic status; Social class - RG
Overview: Around 70 per cent of single women were recorded as having an occupation in each census between 1851 and 1911, however this disguises considerable regional variation.
Single women were employed in a wide range of occupations in nineteenth century Britain. They could be found in factory work, the pottery industry, agriculture, food and drink manufacture, retail, needlework, and other petty trades. By far the largest employment opportunity for single women, however, was the service industry, which accounted for around 50 per cent of single women's work in 1851, but decline set in and by 1911 only 40 per cent of single women were employed in this sector. Although there were opportunities to work in domestic service across the country, these were more plentiful where wealthier people were concentrated, such as the west end of London and in the Home Counties. The textile industry was the second largest employer of young women, and this work was concentrated in the cotton manufacturing areas of Lancashire and West Yorkshire and in the central belt of Scotland.
The regional nature of certain employment opportunities for young women shows up in the graph of the percentages of single women occupied in each type of place (below). In TEXTILE areas the strong demand for young women to work in the cotton and woollen mills led to an employment rate of between 80 and 90 per cent of single women. In contrast there were fewer jobs available in MINING areas, particularly those in England and Wales where not much more than half of all single women were able to find paid work by the end of the nineteenth century.
Widowed women working
Definition: The number of widowed women aged 15 or over recorded as having an occupation (other than housewife or household duties), expressed as a percentage of all widowed women aged 15 or over.
Calculation: The percentage of widowed women working has been calculated using the marital status, age, sex, and occupation fields in the individual level census returns. The number of women aged 15 or over reported to be widowed and in employment was divided by the number of all widowed women aged 15 or over and the result multiplied by 100.
See also: Single women working; Married women working; Domestic service; Textile work; Socio-economic status; Social class - RG.
Overview: In an era before state pensions, widowhood came with a significant risk of poverty, and this forced many widows to seek paid employment. Around half of all widows were recorded as having an occupation between 1851 and 1881, but this fell to around 40 per cent in 1891 (a decline also seen in married women's work). In the beginning of the period a significant number of widows were able to find work in the TEXTILE and straw plaiting areas, producing some regional patterning of the likelihood that widows would be working. However, these opportunities appear to have diminished over the course of the half century, and by 1911 there was little geographic pattern to widows' work (with the exception of continued poor levels of opportunity in MINING areas). Widows were left predominantly doing laundry work, charring (cleaning), shop work and sewing.
Domestic service & Textile work (women)
Definition: Women aged 14-64 working in domestic service, or in the textile industry, as a percentage of all working women aged 14-64.
Calculation: The percentage of women working in domestic service, or in the textile industry, has been calculated using the age and occupation fields in the individual level census returns. The number of women aged 14-64 reported to be employed in domestic service, or in the textile industry, was divided by the number of all women aged 14-64 in employment and the result multiplied by 100.
See also: Married women working; Single women working; Widowed women working; Households with live-in servants.
Overview: The two largest sectors of employment for women in the nineteenth and early twentieth centuries were domestic service and the textile industry. Around 10 per cent of working women in England were employed in the textile industry, with very low levels in Wales. In Scotland around 15 per cent were so employed until 1871, when the percentage started to fall, reaching 5 per cent in 1901. Until the late nineteenth century just under a third of all English, just over a third of Scottish, and four in ten of Welsh women between the ages of 14 and 64 who recorded an occupation, worked as a domestic servant. The decline in servant keeping which started towards the end of the nineteenth century can also be seen in the percentage of households with a live-in servant, although that measure does not take into account the many servants who did not live in their employer's home.
Obviously not every place offered opportunities to work in domestic service or textiles. Unsurprisingly textile work was highly concentrated in the TEXTILE areas (where a large percentage of men were also employed in textiles) of Lancashire and West Yorkshire. In some of these districts over 80 per cent of women who worked were employed in the textile industry. Scottish textile areas were less concentrated: although higher percentages of working women worked in this industry overall between 1851 and 1871, the percentages of women in textile areas who worked in textiles were lower than in England. Nevertheless, the textile industry was still the major source of employment for women in such areas. The corollary of this was that domestic service formed a very small percentage of women's labour in TEXTILE areas throughout the period. Domestic service was also relatively low in OTHER URBAN areas, where there were plentiful other opportunities for work. It must be remembered that proportions of all women who were servants was not necessarily low in these areas: high numbers of women working in other jobs may simply have been depressing the share of servants. For similar reasons, in MINING areas the share of working women who were servants looks quite high, but women were less likely to have been in work at all, so this does not mean that there was a lot of servant-keeping in such places. In fact, households with live-in servants show us that servant keeping was low in all three of these types of area (MINING, TEXTILE and OTHER URBAN). In PROFESSIONAL areas a fairly high percentage of women were working (whether they were married, single or widowed), and these women were also very likely to have been working in service. AGRICULTURAL areas are the one type of area where the percentage of working women who were employed in service was relatively buoyant. The concentration of this change in counties such as Bedfordshire suggests that it was probably due to the decline of alternative employment such as straw-plaiting and does not indicate that the percentage of all women who were working as servants had increased.
Children's work and schooling
Children per teacher
Definition: The number of children aged 4 to 13 years for every teacher.
Calculation: The number of children has been calculated by counting the number of people from the age of 5, up to and including the age of 13. Teachers have been defined by their occupation given in the census. The number of children per teacher has been calculated by dividing the number of children by the number of teachers. It must be remembered that not all children will have been going to school, and not all teachers will have taught children of this age. This measure is therefore more about educational provision than it is about class sizes. There were six Registration Sub-Districts in 1851 and two in 1861 with no resident teachers, and thus no children per teacher.
See also: Children's work
Overview: In 1851 there were around 60 children for every teacher in England, slightly more in Scotland, and over 110 in Wales. But these numbers declined steadily until the turn of the century when there were only around half as many children for every teacher. Interpreting this decline, however, is not straightforward. We do not know whether each child in the census was actually going to school, nor whether they attended full-time or half-time. Therefore very high numbers of children per teacher do not necessarily mean that class sizes were enormous: they could instead mean that some children in the district never attended school, or that many left school before the age of 13. Therefore this measure is more about educational provision than it is about class size, and a decrease in the number of children per teacher reflects improvements in educational provision. It is likely that the trends in the number of children per teacher reflect changes in legislation related to education. The first Education Act in 1870 established school boards which could build and manage schools, and the 1880 Education Act made school compulsory between the ages of 5 and 10 years. It is likely, however, that not all children attended school until the Elementary Education Act of 1891 effectively introduced free education. The effect of these Acts will have been to increase the numbers of teachers, therefore reducing the numbers of children per teacher. Further increases in educational provision are likely to have been associated with rises in the minimum school leaving age to 11 years in 1893 and to 12 years in 1899.
In 1851, the first census year we have available, there were very wide disparities in educational provision across different types of area. There were 33 and 26 children per teacher in English and Scottish PROFESSIONAL areas respectively, but 90, 150 and 186 in English, Scottish and Welsh MINING areas, and high numbers in other industrial areas too. However, the various Education Acts (see above) had the desired effect of improving provision most in places which were initially poorly served. By 1911, although there were still large disparities, they had diminished considerably. The only area which was noticeably poorly served in 1911 was the East End of London. While some children may have left school at a younger age or escaped going at all, and class sizes may have been larger in this poor part of London, the apparent lack of provision may to some extent be an artefact caused by the census recording people where they lived and not where they worked. For the most part London children will have lived close to their school at this time, but the good transport system within the capital meant that their teachers could live in more attractive parts of the capital and commute to work in the East End. Thus the apparent growth of extreme inequality in education apparent in the maps of London may be exaggerated.
Children working
Definition: Number of girls (or boys) aged 10-13 (or 14-18) with an occupation, expressed as a percentage of all girls (or boys) of the same age.
Calculation: The percentage of children working has been calculated using the age, sex, and occupation fields in the individual level census returns. The number of boys (or girls) aged 10-13 (or 14-18) has been calculated by counting the number of boys (or girls) from the age of 10 up to the age of 13 (or from the age of 14 up to the age of 18) who report an employment, dividing this number by the number of all boys (or girls) in that age group and multiplying the result by 100.
See also: Children per teacher
Overview: Despite a common perception that large proportions of Victorian children were earning money, and an absence of compulsory schooling, in 1851 percentages of children aged 10-13 who were working were actually rather small: just 16 per cent of boys and 9 per cent of girls in England and Wales, with slightly lower levels in Scotland. These numbers fell further over the course of the next 60 years as legislation simultaneously increased the minimum working age (to 10 years in 1878, 11 in 1891 and 12 in 1901) and made education compulsory (up to age 10 in 1870, age 11 in 1893 and age 12 in 1899). Older children, aged 14-18, were much more likely to have been working: around 30 per cent of girls (slightly higher in Scotland and lower in Wales) and around 40 per cent of boys (slightly lower in Scotland). The percentages for boys, and girls in Scotland, increased slightly over the period. Although fewer girls than boys were working, they were almost certainly less likely to have been at school. Some girls would have been at school, of course, but those neither in school nor employment were probably taking on housework and domestic duties in the home.
There were considerable regional differences in the opportunities for children to take a paid occupation. The areas with high proportions of young children (aged 10-13) in work are similar to those where high proportions of married women were in work. The graph shows that significant employment opportunities for children were concentrated in the TEXTILE areas of Lancashire and West Yorkshire, where in 1851 and 1861 nearly a quarter of both boys and girls aged 10-13 were in work. MINING districts also provided significant work opportunities, but only for boys, and specific legislation meant that these declined quicker than those in TEXTILE areas. The maps show that there were also other localised pockets of child employment in the early years, such as in the straw plaiting and lace making areas where there were also opportunities for married women at this time. The elimination of work opportunities for children in such places may have had more to do with the decline of those industries than restrictive legislation. By 1911 the only enclave where significant proportions of children aged 10-13 were in paid employment was the TEXTILE areas. The fact that in 1881 around 15 per cent of 10-13 year olds in these areas in England were working, however, does not necessarily mean that they had left school. From 1878 10-14 year olds working in factories were only allowed to be employed for half the day, leaving the other half of the day free to attend lessons.
By the age of 14-18, more girls and boys were recorded as being in paid employment, although regional differences are still evident. The Scottish highlands seem to have had relatively few opportunities for teenagers to work outside the home, even 14-18 year old boys were considerably less likely to be recorded as in paid employment there than elsewhere in Britain. Similar percentages (40-45 per cent) of girls were working in TEXTILE areas as boys. For girls TEXTILE areas had the most extensive work opportunities by some way, but for boys opportunities were more plentiful in MINING areas where there was rather little paid work available for girls. PROFESSIONAL areas had similar percentages (about 30 per cent) of girls and boys in work: for boys, but not for girls, this figure was low compared to other places. Both the sons and daughters of the middle classes and non-manual workers were likely to have stayed at school longer, but there were more employment opportunities for the daughters of the manual classes in these places, and teenage girls were also likely to have migrated in to work as servants for the better-off.